Do managers intentionally use sticky costs to signal private information? Evidence from repurchase tender offers

碩士 === 國立成功大學 === 會計學系 === 104 === The previous academic literature on sticky costs mostly focused on resource adjustment inefficiency or agency problems. However, there is little evidence on whether managers intentionally use sticky costs to signal private information. We find that the degree of st...

Full description

Bibliographic Details
Main Authors: Chien-TingYen, 顏千婷
Other Authors: Ting-Kai Chou
Format: Others
Language:zh-TW
Published: 2016
Online Access:http://ndltd.ncl.edu.tw/handle/945f3r
id ndltd-TW-104NCKU5385018
record_format oai_dc
spelling ndltd-TW-104NCKU53850182019-05-15T22:54:09Z http://ndltd.ncl.edu.tw/handle/945f3r Do managers intentionally use sticky costs to signal private information? Evidence from repurchase tender offers 成本僵固性與公開收購之關聯性 Chien-TingYen 顏千婷 碩士 國立成功大學 會計學系 104 The previous academic literature on sticky costs mostly focused on resource adjustment inefficiency or agency problems. However, there is little evidence on whether managers intentionally use sticky costs to signal private information. We find that the degree of sticky costs is significantly higher for fixed-price repurchase tender offers than Dutch-auction tender offers. In other words, managers who adopt fixed-price repurchase tender offers intentionally use sticky costs to signal managerial optimism. Furthermore, we also find that the signaling effect of sticky costs is stronger for firms with less analyst coverage and lower institutional ownership. Overall, our evidence show that managers could use sticky costs as a signal of business prospects. Ting-Kai Chou 周庭楷 2016 學位論文 ; thesis 26 zh-TW
collection NDLTD
language zh-TW
format Others
sources NDLTD
description 碩士 === 國立成功大學 === 會計學系 === 104 === The previous academic literature on sticky costs mostly focused on resource adjustment inefficiency or agency problems. However, there is little evidence on whether managers intentionally use sticky costs to signal private information. We find that the degree of sticky costs is significantly higher for fixed-price repurchase tender offers than Dutch-auction tender offers. In other words, managers who adopt fixed-price repurchase tender offers intentionally use sticky costs to signal managerial optimism. Furthermore, we also find that the signaling effect of sticky costs is stronger for firms with less analyst coverage and lower institutional ownership. Overall, our evidence show that managers could use sticky costs as a signal of business prospects.
author2 Ting-Kai Chou
author_facet Ting-Kai Chou
Chien-TingYen
顏千婷
author Chien-TingYen
顏千婷
spellingShingle Chien-TingYen
顏千婷
Do managers intentionally use sticky costs to signal private information? Evidence from repurchase tender offers
author_sort Chien-TingYen
title Do managers intentionally use sticky costs to signal private information? Evidence from repurchase tender offers
title_short Do managers intentionally use sticky costs to signal private information? Evidence from repurchase tender offers
title_full Do managers intentionally use sticky costs to signal private information? Evidence from repurchase tender offers
title_fullStr Do managers intentionally use sticky costs to signal private information? Evidence from repurchase tender offers
title_full_unstemmed Do managers intentionally use sticky costs to signal private information? Evidence from repurchase tender offers
title_sort do managers intentionally use sticky costs to signal private information? evidence from repurchase tender offers
publishDate 2016
url http://ndltd.ncl.edu.tw/handle/945f3r
work_keys_str_mv AT chientingyen domanagersintentionallyusestickycoststosignalprivateinformationevidencefromrepurchasetenderoffers
AT yánqiāntíng domanagersintentionallyusestickycoststosignalprivateinformationevidencefromrepurchasetenderoffers
AT chientingyen chéngběnjiānggùxìngyǔgōngkāishōugòuzhīguānliánxìng
AT yánqiāntíng chéngběnjiānggùxìngyǔgōngkāishōugòuzhīguānliánxìng
_version_ 1719136848387768320